Today's puzzler: The family (plus a couple of interlopers) is gathered
for a holiday dinner.
Grandpa stands up to speak. "In this wonderful country," he says, "our
family has been
blessed. We have prospered. Our wonderful children have married wonderful
partners
and given us many wonderful grandchildren. Your grandmother and I love
you all very much."
He then goes around the table giving each family member and in-law
(but not, alas, the interlopers) a kiss and an envelope containing
two checks.
Question: What was the amount on the checks?
(Tick. Tock. Tick. Tock. Tick. Tock. Tick. Tock.)
Time's up. The answer: The checks were all for $10,000.
"Egad, Holmes! How in blazes did you know that?"
"Elementary, my dear Watson. The two checks were the vital clue. Why
two? Because the law
exempts gifts of up to $10,000 a year, per recipient, from the confounded
Estate and Gift Tax—or
'death tax,' as the Republicans so wittily call it. The grandparents
were clearly attempting to take
maximum advantage of this law by issuing separate checks from each
of them to each family member.
Inclusion of the in-laws merely confirms the hypothesis.
"Just think, Watson! If Grandpa and Grandma do this for just 10 years,
with four children, their spouses,
and 12 grandchildren, $4 million will escape the clutches of the big-spending
Democrats!"
Even by current low standards, the campaign to abolish the estate tax
has been remarkably
disingenuous. It does not take Sherlock Holmes to know that with a
minimum of foresight and offspring,
and no fancy footwork, you can pass on several million dollars tax-free—not
the official exemption of
$675,000 (already scheduled to rise to $1 million).
But the most deceptive argument in the debate is that it is unfair to
tax the same money twice—once
when you earn it and again when you die. Writing in last Friday's Wall
Street Journal, economist
Martin Feldstein grandly calculates that if you start with $1,000,
you pay income tax on it, you sock it
away for 30 years and pay income tax on the interest, then you die
and your estate pays the death tax
... the effective tax rate on your $1,000 is a shocking 77 percent.
Feldstein calls this "very unfair." And maybe it would be, if it ever
happened. Professor Feldstein has
surely made far more than $1 million over the years telling wealthy
Republicans things they like to hear.
May he live long and prosper. But were he struck down tomorrow—possibly
by the sight of President
Clinton vetoing Congress' estate tax abolition bill—I bet there aren't
many dollars in his estate that will
have come through a tax gantlet of anything like 77 percent.
The truth is that most of the accumulated wealth that is subject to
the estate tax was never taxed at all
as income. Repeat: never taxed at all. If the estate tax is abolished,
the average billionaire's
billion-and-first dollar will be subject to a cumulative tax rate of
zero. By comparison, the very first
dollar earned by someone frying burgers at McDonald's is subject to
the FICA tax of about 15 percent.
(Investment income is exempt from FICA.) Tendentious comparisons of
this sort are often dismissed
these days as outmoded "class warfare," unless the complaint is about
unfairness to the rich.
Nevertheless, taxing Dollar one at 15 percent and Dollar billion-and-one
at zero percent seems,
to quote Feldstein, "very unfair."
The reason most inherited wealth was never taxed as income is that it
consists of so-called "appreciated
property." The simplest example is shares of stock. If you buy at $100
and die at $120, your $20 profit
is never taxed as income. When your heirs sell the stock, their profit
is calculated as if they bought at
$120.
Stocks aren't the best example, though. The best examples are the poster
children of the campaign to
abolish the estate tax: farmers, "small"-business owners, and people
who have suffered the terrible
tragedy of buying a house cheap and watching it become phenomenally
valuable. When the owners die,
not a penny of the value of these farms, businesses, and houses has
ever been subject to the income
tax. We can have a metaphysical argument about whether this is fair
or not. But it is simply wrong to
say that subjecting these assets to the estate tax means taxing them
twice.
Naturally, Feldstein claims that abolishing the estate tax would actually
increase total tax revenues. By
cherished Republican tradition, this Free Lunch Guarantee must be part
of the argument for any tax cut.
Feldstein—actually, the most sober of leading Republican economists—at
first hangs a nervous little
"probably" on it, but the assertion gains certitude with repetition.
So, how does he figure? The usual free-lunch argument is that lowering
the tax on some activity will
stimulate more of that activity. But the proposition that lower death
duties will encourage more people
to die is both implausible and unappealing. There's also the problem
that a tax rate of zero will not bring
in any revenue no matter how stimulating it may be.
Feldstein, undeterred, tries a new twist: The estate tax, he argues,
encourages people to make
deductible contributions to charity, so abolishing the estate tax will
make them stingier, which will mean
fewer income-tax dollars lost to the charitable deduction. Possibly
true, but I'd like to see the
Republicans this fall campaigning on a call to increase tax revenues
by discouraging donations to
charity. And, as a special treat, Feldstein throws in a similar argument
that abolishing the estate tax will
encourage rich parents to hoard their wealth until the end, rather
than helping out their children in lower
income-tax brackets. Another good one for the campaign trail.
Grandpa is right: This country has been good to most of us—and spectacularly
good to a few.
Is it really so unreasonable for the luckiest 2 percent to pay some
taxes on their good fortunes
at least once in a lifetime? Even if they happen to be farmers or small-business
owners or winners
of the real-estate lottery?